Preview

Moscow University Economics Bulletin

Advanced search

Distribution of creative works protected by copyright

https://doi.org/10.38050/01300105202156

Abstract

This article addresses possible structural alternatives for the dissemination of the results of intellectual activity (RIA), which reflect setting of optimal price and level of technical protection. The paper argues that digital piracy is not always a negative factor for the author or copyright owner but may be a signal indicating an inefficiently of RIA distributing method. The developed model demonstrates the choice of RIA distribution strategy depending on various factors: author's popularity, the difference in quality between the original RIA and pirated copy, legal protection level. The findings regarding the possibilities of combining legal and technical protection, consumer behavior and the positive effects of digital piracy will help the regulator to apply more effective measures. The article is written on the basis of the RANEPA state assignment research program.

About the Author

A. A. Morsanova
Lomonosov Moscow State University; RANEPA
Russian Federation

Moscow



References

1. Arutyunyan, V.A. (2019). Creative Commons licenses in Russia. Economics, Entrepreneurship and Law, 9(4), 617–628.

2. Civil Code of the Russian Federation (part four) of December 18, 2006 № 230-FZ (as amended on December 30, 2020) (as amended and supplemented, entered into force on January 17, 2021).

3. Elchaninova, N.B. (2016). Problems of legal protection of intellectual property on the Internet. Society: politics, economics, law, 12, 11–13.

4. Kartskhia, A. (2017). Digital imperative: new technologies create a new reality. Intellectual property. Copyright and Related Rights, 8, 17–26.

5. Kuramagomedov, R. S. (2014). The main areas of technical means application of protecting copyright and related rights. System Technologies, 10, 68–75.

6. Morosanova, A.A., & Meleshkina, A.I. (2017). The impact of piracy and technical protection of the results of intellectual activity on public welfare. Moscow University Bulletin. Series 6: Economics, 1, 62–85.

7. Novoselova, L.A., & Grin, O. S. (2018). The effectiveness of legal protection of objects of intellectual rights: administrative barriers. Right. Journal of the Higher School of Economics, 2, 23–32.

8. Shastitko, A.E., Kurdin, A.A., & Komkova, A.A. (2014). How to protect the results of intellectual activity. Social Sciences and Modernity, 2, 17–33.

9. Shastitko, A. E., Kurdin, A.A., & Morosanova, A.A. (2016). Product boundaries of the software market in the context of antimonopoly legislation application. Moscow University Bulletin. Series 6: Economics, 6, 39–56.

10. Shulga, I.E., Eliseev, A. N., & Kuznetsova, T.A. (2014). Institutional alternatives for product quality assurance and accurate contract execution. Moscow University Bulletin. Series 6: Economics, 4, 3–20.

11. Art of the Possible. (2020). The U. S. Chamber of Commerce Global Innovation Policy Center released the eighth annual International IP Index 2020. https://www.uschamber.com/sites/default/files/023881_gipc_ip_index_2020_fullreport_final.pdf

12. Arrow, K. (1962). Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention, in Nelson, R. (ed.), The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity, Princeton, Princeton University Press, 609–625.

13. Bae, S.-H., & Choi, J. P. (2006). A Model of Piracy. Information Economics and Policy, 18, 303-320. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.infoecopol.2006.02.002

14. Banerjee, D. (2003). Software piracy: a strategic analysis and policy instruments. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 21, 1, 97–127.

15. Belleflamme, P. (2002). Pricing Information Goods in the Presence of Copying. Working Papers 463, Queen Mary University of London, School of Economics and Finance.

16. Belleflamme, P., & Picard, P. M. (2007). Piracy and competition. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 16, 351–83. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1530-9134.2007.00142.x

17. Bennett, V., & Seamans, R., & Zhu, F. (2014). Cannibalization and option value effects of secondary markets: Evidence from the US concert industry. Strategic Management Journal, 3. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2299

18. Bhattacharjee, S., & Gopal, R. D., & Sanders, G. L. (2003). Digital music and online sharing: Software piracy 2.0? Communications of the ACM, 46(7), 107–111. doi:10.1145/792704.792707

19. Chen, Y., & Png, I. (2003). Information goods pricing and copyright enforcement: welfare analysis, Information Systems Research, 14, 107–23. doi: 10.1287/isre.14.1.107.14762

20. Christin, N., & Weigend A. S., & Chuang, J. (2005). Content availability, pollution and poisoning in file sharing peer-to-peer networks. EC’05: Proceedings of the 6th ACM Conference on Electronic Commerce, New York: ACM Press. 68–77.

21. Conner, K. R., & Rumelt, R. P. (1991). Software Piracy — An Analysis of Protection Strategies. Management Science, 37, 125–139. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.37.2.125

22. Cox, J., & Collins, A. (2014). Sailing in the same ship? differences in factors motivating piracy of music and movie content. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics, 50, 70–76. doi: 10.1016/j.socec.2014.02.010.

23. European Union Intellectual Property Office. (2019). Online Copyright Infringement In the European Union. Music, Films and TV (2017–2018),Trends and Drivers. Doi: 10.2814/907556

24. Florian, S., & Piolatto, A. (2011). A model of music piracy with popularity-dependent copying costs. Working Papers. Serie AD 201-08, Instituto Valenciano de Investigaciones Económicas, S.A. (Ivie).

25. Ginarte, J. C., & Park, W. G. (1997). Determinants of patent rights: A crossnational study. Research Policy 26 (3). 283–301. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0048-7333(97)00022-X

26. Gopal, R., & Bhattacharjee, S., & Sanders, G. (2006). Do Artists Benefit from Online Music Sharing? The Journal of Business, 79, 1503–1533. https://doi.org/10.1086/500683

27. Hirshleifer, J., & Riley, J. G. (1992). The Analytics of Uncertainty and Information. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. New York,465 pp., ISBN 0-521-2395 6-7.

28. International Property Rights Index 2019. (2019). Property Right Alliance, PRI Partner Organizations. https://atr-ipri2017.s3.amazonaws.com/uploads/IPRI_2019_ES_Report.pdf

29. Kim, A., & Dey, D., (2014). The 'Invisible Hand' of Piracy: An Economic Analysis of the Information-Goods Supply Chain. SSRN Electronic Journal. https://www.researchgate.net/publication/272302509_The_%27Invisible_Hand%27_of_Piracy_An_Economic_Analysis_of_the_Information-Goods_Supply_Chain

30. LaRose,R.,Y., & Lai, R., & Lange,B., & Wu. Y. (2005). Sharing or piracy? An exploration of downloading behavior. Journal of Computer Mediated Communication 11(1) (Article 1) http://jcmc.indiana.edu/vol11/issue1/larose.html.

31. Liebowitz, S. (1985). Copying and Indirect Appropriability: Photocopying of Journals. Journal of Political Economy, 93, 945–957. https://doi.org/10.1086/261343.

32. Liebowitz, S. J. (2006). File Sharing: Creative Destruction or Just Plain Destruction?. Journal of Law and Economics, 49(1), 1–28. https://doi.org/10.1086/503518

33. Martínez-Sánchez, F. (2020). Preventing commercial piracy when consumers are loss averse, Information Economics and Policy, Elsevier, vol. 53(C). doi: 10.1016/j.infoecopol.2020.100896

34. Mortimer, J., & Nosko, C., & Sorensen, A. (2012). Supply responses to digital distribution: Recorded music and live performances. Information Economics and Policy, 24, 3–14. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1703041.

35. Mussa, M., & Rosen, S. (1978). Monopoly and Product Quality. Journal of Economic Theory, 18, 301–317. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(78)90085-6

36. Novos, I.E,. & Waldman, M. (1984). The Effects of Increased Copyright Protection: An Analytic Approach. Journal of Political Economy, 2, 236–246. https://doi.org/10.1086/261222

37. Oberholzer-Gee, F., & Strumpf, K. (2007). The effect of file sharing on record sales: An empirical analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 115, 1–42. https://doi.org/10.1086/511995

38. Parameswaran, M., Susarla, A., & Whinston, A.B. (2001). P2P networking: An information-sharing alternative. IEEE Computer 34(7), 31–38. doi:10.1109/2.933501

39. Peitz, M., & Waelbroeck, P. (2006). Why the Music Industry May Gain from Free Downloading — the Role of Sampling. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24, 907–913. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2005.10.006

40. Peitz, M., & Waelbroeck, P. (2004). File-Sharing, Sampling, and Music Distribution. International University in Germany Working Paper No. 26/2004, http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.652743

41. Prasad, A., & Mahajan, V. (2003). How many pirates should a software firm tolerate? An analysis of piracy protection on the diffusion of software. International Journal of Research in Marketing, 20, 337–353. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijresmar.2003.02.001.

42. Rapp, R. T., & Rozek, R. P. (1990). Benefits and costs of intellectual property protection in developing countries. Journal of World Trade 75/77: 75–102

43. Rasch, A., & Wenzel, T. (2013). Piracy in a two-sided software market. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 88, 78–89. 10.1016/j.jebo.2013.01.009.

44. Report on the protection and enforcement of intellectual property rights in third countries. (2019). European Commission. https://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2020/january/tradoc_158561.pdf

45. Rob, R., & Waldfogel, J. (2006). Piracy on the high C’s: Music downloading, sales displacement, and social welfare in a sample of college students. Journal of Law and Economics, 49, 29–62. https://doi.org/10.1086/430809

46. Shy, O., & Thisse, J. (1999) A strategic approach to software protection, Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 8, 163–90. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1430-9134.1999.00163.x

47. Slive, J., & Bernhardt, D. (1998). Pirated for Profit. Canadian Journal of Economics, 31, 4, 886–899. https://doi.org/10.2307/136498

48. Smarzynska, B. K. (2004). Composition of foreign direct investment and protection of intellectual property rights in transition economies. European Economic Review, 48(1), 39–62. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0014-2921(02)00257-X

49. Smith, M., & Telang, R. (2009). Competing with free: The impact of movie broadcasts on DVD sales and Internet piracy. MIS Quarterly, 33, 321–338. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1028306

50. Takeyama, L. N. (2003). Piracy, Asymmetric Information and Product Quality. The economics.

51. Takeyama, L. N. (1994). The welfare implications of unauthorized reproduction of intellectual property in the presence of network externalities, Journal of Industrial Economics, 42, 155–66.

52. Unlu, V., & Hess, T. (2003). The optimal level of technical copyright protection: A gametheoretic approach. Working Paper, Institute for Information Systems and New Media, Munich School of Management, No. 9.

53. Waldfogel, J. (2011). Bye, Bye, American Pie: The Supply of New Recorded Music since Napster. NBER Working Paper No. 16882. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1789463

54. Yoon, K. (2002). The Optimal Level of Copyright Protection. Information Economics and Policy 14, 327–348. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-6245(01)00062-2

55. Zentner, A. (2006). Measuring the effect of file sharing on music purchases. Journal of Law and Economics, 49, 63–90. https://doi.org/10.1086/501082

56. Zhang, L. (2014). Intellectual Property Strategy and the Long Tail: Evidence from the Recorded Music Industry. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2515581. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2515581


Review

For citations:


Morsanova A.A. Distribution of creative works protected by copyright. Moscow University Economics Bulletin. 2021;(5):110-135. (In Russ.) https://doi.org/10.38050/01300105202156

Views: 267


Creative Commons License
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 License.


ISSN 0130-0105 (Print)